2016-08-12

Created page with "{{header | title = Das Kapital Volume Two | author = | override_author = by Karl Marx and Fredrick Engels | section = C..."

New page

{{header

| title = Das Kapital Volume Two

| author = | override_author = by [[Author:Karl Marx|Karl Marx]] and [[Author:Friedrich Engels|Fredrick Engels]]

| section = Chapter 12: The Working Period

| previous = [[../Chapter 11|Chapter 11]]

| next = [[../Chapter 13|Chapter 13]]

| year = 1893

| notes =

}}

<p class="fst">

Let us take two branches of business with working-days of equal length,

say, of ten hours each, one of them a cotton spinning-mill, the other a

locomotive works. In one of these branches a definite quantity of finished

product, cotton yarn, is turned out daily or weekly; in the other, the

labour-process has to be repeated for perhaps three months in order to manufacture

a finished product, a locomotive. In one case the product is discrete in

nature; and each day or week the same labour starts over again. In the other

case the labour-process is continuous and extends over a rather great number

of daily labour-processes which, in their interconnection, in the continuity

of their operation, bring forth a finished product only after a rather

long period of time. Although the duration of the daily labour-process

is the same here, there is a very marked difference in the duration of

the productive act, i.e., in the duration of the repeated labour-processes

required to get out a finished product, to market it as a commodity, hence

to convert it from productive to commodity-capital. The distinction between

fixed and circulating capital has nothing to do with this. The distinction

indicated would exist even if the very same proportions of fixed and circulating

capital were employed in both branches of production.</p>

<p>These differences in the duration of the productive act can be

observed not alone between different spheres of production, but also within

one and the same sphere of production, depending on the amount of product

to be turned out. An ordinary dwelling house is built in less time than

a large factory and therefore requires fewer continuous labour-processes.

While the building of a locomotive takes three months, that of an armoured

man-of-war requires one year or more. It takes nearly a year to produce

grain and several years to raise big cattle, while timber-growing needs

from twelve to one hundred years. A few months will suffice for a country

road, while a railway is a job of years. An ordinary carpet is made in

about a week, but a <em>Gobelin</em> takes years, etc. Hence the time consumed

in the performance of the productive act varies infinitely.</p>

<p>The difference in the duration of the productive act must evidently

give rise to a difference in the velocity of the turnover, if invested

capitals are equal, in other words, must make a difference in the time

for which a certain capital is advanced. Assume that a spinning-mill and

a locomotive works employ the same amount of capital, that the ratio of

their constant to their variable capital is the same, likewise the proportion

between the fixed and circulating parts of the capitals, and that lastly

their working-day is of equal length and its division into necessary and

surplus-labour the same. In order to eliminate, furthermore, all the circumstances

arising out of the process of circulation and having no bearing on the

present case, let us suppose that both the yarn and the locomotive are

made to order and will be paid on delivery of the finished product. At

the end of the week, on delivery of the finished yarn, the spinning-mill

owner recovers his outlay for circulating capital (leaving the surplus-value

out of consideration), likewise the fixed capital’s wear and tear incorporated

in the value of the yarn. He can therefore repeat the same circuit anew

with the same capital. It has completed its turnover. The locomotive manufacturer

on the other hand must lay out ever new capital for wages and raw material

every week for three months in succession, and it is only after three months,

after the delivery of the locomotive, that the circulating capital, meanwhile

gradually laid out in one and the same productive act for the manufacture

of one and the same commodity, once more exists in a form in which it can

renew its circuit. The wear and tear of his machinery during these three

months is likewise replaced only now. The expenditure of the one is made

for one week, that of the other is the weekly expenditure multiplied by

twelve. All other circumstances being assumed as equal, the one must have

twelve times as much circulating capital at his disposal as the other.</p>

<p>It is however immaterial here that the capitals advanced weekly

are equal. Whatever the amount of the advanced capital, it is advanced

for only one week in the one case and for twelve weeks in the other, and

the above periods must respectively elapse before it can be used for a

new operation, before the same operation can be repeated with it, or a

different one inaugurated.</p>

<p>The difference in the velocity of the turnover, or in the length

of time for which the individual capital must be advanced before the same

capital-value can be employed in a new labour- or self-expansion process,

arises here from the following circumstances:</p>

<p>Granted the manufacture of a locomotive or of any other machine

requires 100 working-days. So far as the labourers employed in the manufacture

of yarn or the building of locomotives are concerned, 100 working-days

constitute in either case a discontinuous (discrete) magnitude, consisting,

according to our assumption, of 100 consecutive separate ten-hour labour-processes.

But so far as the product — the machine — is concerned, these 100 working-days form a continuous magnitude, a working-day of 1,000 working-hours, one

single connected act of production. I call such a working-day which is

composed of a more or less numerous succession of connected working days

a <em>working period</em>. When we speak of a working-day we mean the length

of working time during which the labourer must daily spend his labour-power,

must work day by day. But when we speak of a working period we mean the

number of connected working-days required in a certain branch of industry

for the manufacture of a finished product. In this case the product of

every working-day is but a partial one, which is further worked upon from

day to day and only at the end of the longer or shorter working period

receives its finished form, is a finished use-value.</p>

<p>Interruptions, disturbances of the process of social production,

in consequence for instance of crises, have therefore very different effects

on labour-products of a discrete nature and on those that require for their

production a prolonged connected period. In the one case all that happens

is that today’s production of a certain quantity of yarn, coal, etc., is

not followed by tomorrow’s new production of yarn, coal, etc. Not so in

the case of ships, buildings, railways, etc. Here it is not only the day’s

work but an entire connected act of production that is interrupted. If

the job is not continued, the means of production and labour already consumed

in its production are wasted. Even if it is resumed, a deterioration has

inevitably set in in the meantime.</p>

<p>For the entire length of the working period, the part of the value

daily transferred to the product by the fixed capital accumulates in layers,

as it were, until the product is finished. And here the difference between

fixed and circulating capital is revealed at the same time in its practical

significance. Fixed capital is advanced in the process of production for

a comparatively long period; it need not be renewed until after the expiration

of perhaps a period of several years. Whether a steam-engine transfers

its value daily piecemeal to some yarn, the product of a discrete labour-process,

or for three months to a locomotive, the product of a continuous act of

production, is immaterial as far as laying out the capital required for

the purchase of the steam-engine is concerned. In the one case its value

flows back in small doses, for instance weekly, in the other case in larger

quantities, for instance quarterly. But in either case the renewal of the

steam-engine may take place only after twenty years. So long as every individual

period within which the value of the steam-engine is returned piecemeal

by the sale of the product is shorter than the lifetime of the engine itself,

the latter continues to function in the process of production for several

working periods.</p>

<p>It is different with the circulating components of the advanced

capital. The labour-power bought for a definite week is expended in the

course of the same week and is materialised in the product. It must be

paid for at the end of the week. And this investment of capital in labour-power

is repeated every week during the three months; yet the expenditure of

this part of the capital during the week does not enable the capitalist

to settle for the purchase of the labour the following week. Every week

additional capital must be expended to pay for labour-power, and, leaving

aside the question of credit, the capitalist must be able to lay out wages

for three months, even if he pays them only in weekly doses. It is the

same with the other portion of circulating capital, the raw and auxiliary

materials. One layer of labour after another is piled up on the product.

It is not alone the value of the expended labour-power that is continually

being transferred to the product during the labour-process, but also surplus-value.

This product, however, is unfinished, it has not yet the form of a finished

commodity, hence it cannot yet circulate. This applies likewise to the

capital-value transferred in layers from the raw and auxiliary materials

to the product.</p>

<p>Depending on the length of the working period exacted by the specific

nature of the product or by the useful effect to be achieved in its manufacture,

a continuous additional investment of circulating capital (wages and raw

and auxiliary materials) is required, no part of which is in a form capable

of circulation and hence of promoting a renewal of the same operation.

Every part is on the contrary held fast successively in the sphere of production

as a component of the nascent product, tied up in the form of productive

capital. Now, the time of turnover is equal to the sum of the time of production

and the time of circulation of the capital. Hence a prolongation of the

time of production reduces the velocity of the turnover quite as much as

a prolongation of the time of circulation. In the present case however

the following two points must be noted:</p>

<p>Firstly: The prolonged stay in the sphere of production. The capital

advanced for instance for labour, raw material, etc., during the first

week, as well as the portions of value transferred to the product by the

fixed capital, are held fast in the sphere of production for the entire

term of three months, and, being incorporated in an only nascent, still

unfinished product, cannot pass into circulation as commodities.</p>

<p>Secondly: Since the working period required for the performance

of the productive act lasts three months, and forms in fact only one connected

labour-process, a new dose of circulating capital must be continually added

week after week to the preceding amount. The total of the successively

advanced additional capital grows therefore with the length of the working

period.</p>

<p>We have assumed that capitals of equal size are invested in spinning

and machine-building, that these capitals contain equal proportions of

constant and variable, fixed and circulating capital, that the working-days

are of equal length, in brief, that all conditions are equal except the

duration of the working period. In the first week, the outlay for both

is the same, but the product of the spinner can be sold and the proceeds

of the sale used to buy new labour-power, new raw materials, etc.; in short,

production can be resumed on the same scale. The machine-manufacturer on

the other hand cannot reconvert the circulating capital expended in the

first week into money and resume operations with it until three months

later, when his product is finished. There is therefore first a difference

in the return of the identical quantities of capital invested. But in the

second place identical amounts of productive capital are employed during

the three months in both spinning and machine-building. However the magnitude

of the outlay of capital in the case of the yarn manufacturer is quite

different from that of the machine-builder; for in the one case the same

capital is rapidly renewed and the same operation can therefore be repeated,

while in the other case the renewal of the capital is relatively slow,

so that ever new quantities of capital must be added to the old up to the

time of its renewal. Consequently there is a difference not only in the

length of time of renewal of definite portions of capital, or in the length

of time for which the capital is advanced, but also in the quantity of

the capital to be advanced according to the duration of the labour-process

(although the capitals employed daily or weekly are equal). This circumstance

is worthy of note for the reason that the term of the advance may be prolonged,

as we shall see in the cases treated in the next chapter, without thereby

necessitating a corresponding increase in the amount of the capital to

be advanced. The capital must be advanced for a longer time, and a larger

amount of capital is tied up in the form of productive capital.</p>

<p>At the less developed stages of capitalist production, undertakings

requiring a long working period, and hence a large investment of capital

for a long time, such as the building of roads, canals, etc., especially

when they can be carried out only on a large scale, are either not carried

out on a capitalist basis at all, but rather at communal or state expense

(in earlier times generally by forced labour, so far as the labour-power

was concerned). Or objects whose production requires a lengthy working

period are fabricated only for the smallest part by recourse to the private

means of the capitalist himself. For instance, in the building of a house,

the private person for whom it is built makes a number of partial advance

payments to the building contractor. He therefore actually pays for the

house piecemeal, in proportion as the productive process progresses. But

in the advanced capitalist era, when on the one hand huge capitals are

concentrated in the hands of single individuals, while on the other the

associated capitalist (joint-stock companies) appears side by side with

the individual capitalist and a credit system has simultaneously been developed,

a capitalist building contractor builds only in exceptional cases on the

order of private individuals. His business nowadays is to build whole rows

of houses and entire sections of cities for the market, just as it is the

business of individual capitalists to build railways as contractors.</p>

<p>To what extent capitalist production has revolutionised the building

of houses in London is shown by the testimony of a builder before the banking

committee of 1857. When he was young, he said, houses were generally built

to order and the payments made in instalments to the contractor as certain

stages of the building were being completed. Very little was built on speculation.

Contractors used to assent to such operations mainly to keep their men

in constant employment and thus hold them together. In the last forty years

all that has changed. Very little is now built to order. Anyone wanting

a new house picks one from among those built on speculation or still in

process of construction. The builder no longer works for his customers

but for the market. Like every other industrial capitalist he is compelled

to have finished articles in the market. While formerly a builder had perhaps

three or four houses building at a time for speculation, he must now buy

a large plot of ground (which in continental language means rent it for

ninety-nine years, as a rule), build from 100 to 200 houses on it, and

thus embark on an enterprise which exceeds his resources twenty to fifty

times. The funds are procured through mortgaging and the money is placed

at the disposal of the contractor as the buildings proceed. Then, if a

crisis comes along and interrupts the payment of the advance instalments,

the entire enterprise generally collapses. At best, the houses remain unfinished

until better times arrive; at the worst they are sold at auction for half

their cost. Without speculative building, and on a large scale at that,

no contractor can get along today. The profit from just building is extremely

small. His main profit comes from raising the ground-rent, from careful

selection and skilled utilisation of the building terrain. It is by this

method of speculation anticipating the demand for houses that almost the

whole Belgravia and Tyburnia, and the countless thousands of villas round

London have been built. (Abbreviated from the Report of the Select Committee

on Bank Acts, Part I, 1857, Evidence, Questions 5413-18; 5435-36.)</p>

<p>The execution of enterprises requiring working periods of considerable

length and operations on a large scale does not fall fully within the province

of capitalist production until the concentration of capital becomes very

pronounced, and the development of the credit system offers to the capitalist,

on the other hand, the convenient expedient of advancing and thus risking

other people’s capital instead of his own. It goes without saying that

whether the capital advanced in production belongs to him who uses it or

does not has no effect on the velocity or time of turnover.</p>

<p>Conditions such as cooperation, division of labour, application

of machinery, which augment the product of the individual working-day,

shorten at the same time the working period of connected acts of production.

Thus machinery shortens the building time of houses, bridges, etc.; mowers

and threshers reduce the working period required to transform ripe grain

into the finished product. Greater speed due to improved shipbuilding cuts

the turnover time of capital invested in shipping. But improvements that

shorten the working period and thereby the time during which circulating

capital must be advanced generally go hand in hand with an increased outlay

of fixed capital.</p>

<p>On the other hand the working period in certain branches of production

may be diminished by the mere extension of cooperation. The completion

of a railway is expedited by setting afoot huge armies of labourer and

thus tackling the job in many spots at once. The time of turnover is lessened

in that case by an increase of the advanced capital. More means of production

and more labour-power must be united under the command of the capitalist.</p>

<p>Whereas the shortening of the working period is thus mostly connected

with an increase of the capital advanced for this abbreviated time — the

shorter the term of advance the greater the capital advanced — it must

here be recalled that regardless of the existing amount of social capital,

the essential point is the degree in which the means of production and

subsistence, or the disposal of them, are scattered or concentrated in

the hands of individual capitalists, in other words, the degree of concentration

of capitals already attained. Inasmuch as credit promotes, accelerates

and enhances the concentration of capital in one hand, it contributes to

the shortening of the working period and thus of the turnover time.</p>

<p>In branches of production in which the working period, whether

continuous or discontinuous, is prescribed by definite natural conditions,

no shortening by the above-mentioned means can take place. Says W. Walter

Good, in his <em>Political, Agricultural, and Commercial Fallacies</em> (London,

1866, p. 325):</p>

<p class="indentb">“In regard to quicker returns, this term cannot be made

to apply to corn crops, as one return only can be made per annum. In respect

to stock, we will simply ask, how is the return of two- and three-year-old

sheep, and four- and five-year-old oxen to be quickened.”</p>

<p class="fst">

The necessity of securing ready money as soon as possible (for

instance to meet fixed obligations, such as taxes, ground-rent, etc.) solves

this problem, e.g., by selling or slaughtering cattle before they have

reached the economically normal age, to the great detriment of agriculture.

This also brings about in the end a rise in the price of meat.</p>

<p class="indentb">“Men who have mainly reared cattle for supplying the pastures of the Midland counties in summer, and the yards of the eastern counties in winter ... have become so crippled through the uncertainty and lowness in the prices of corn that

they are glad to take advantage of the high prices of butter and cheese;

the former they take to market weekly to help to pay current expenses,

and draw on the other from some factor, who takes the cheese when fit to

move, and, of course, nearly at his own price. For this reason, remembering

that farming is governed by the principles of Political Economy, the calves

which used to come south from the dairying counties for rearing, are now

largely sacrificed at times at a week and ten days old, in the shambles

of Birmingham, Manchester, Liverpool, and other large neighbouring towns.

If, however, malt had been free from duty, not only would farmers have

made more profit and therefore been able to keep their stock till it got

older and heavier, but it would have been substituted for milk for rearing

by men who did not keep cows, and thus the present alarming scarcity of

young cattle which has befallen the nation would have been largely averted.

What these little men now say, in reply to recommendations to rear, is,

‘We know very well it would pay to rear on milk, but it would first require

us to put our hands in our purse, which we cannot do, and then we should

have to wait a long time for a return, instead of getting it at once by

dairying.’“ (<em>Ibid</em>., pp. 11 and 12.)</p>

<p class="fst">If the prolongation of the turnover has such consequences for

the small English farmers, it is easy to see what disarrangement it must

produce among the small peasants of the continent.</p>

<p>The part of the value transferred in layers by the fixed capital

to the product accumulates, and the return of this part is delayed, in

proportion to the length of the working period and thus also of the period

of time required for the completion of the commodity capable of circulation.

But this delay does not cause a renewed outlay of fixed capital. The machine

continues to function in the process of production, whether the replacement

of its wear and tear in the form of money returns slowly or rapidly. It

is different with the circulating capital. Not only must capital be tied

up for a rather long time, in proportion to the length of the working period,

but new capital must be continually advanced in the shape of wages, and

raw and auxiliary materials. A delayed return has therefore a different

effect on each. No matter whether the return is rapid or slow, the fixed

capital continues to function. But the circulating capital becomes unable

to perform its functions, if the return is delayed, if it is tied up in

the form of unsold, or unfinished and as yet unsaleable products, and if

no additional capital is at hand for its renewal in kind.</p>

<p class="indentb">“While the peasant farmer starves, his cattle thrive. Repeated

showers had fallen in the country, and the forage was abundant. The Hindoo

peasant will perish by hunger beside a fat bullock. The prescriptions of

superstition, which appear cruel to the individual, are conservative for

the community; and the preservation of the labouring cattle secures the

power of cultivation, and the sources of future life and wealth. It may

sound harsh and sad to say so, but in India it is more easy to replace

a man than an ox.” (Return, East India, Madras and Orissa Famine. No. 4,

p. 44.)</p>

<p class="fst">Compare with the preceding the utterance of Manava Dharma Sastra,

[Manava Dharma Sastra or Manu laws — an ancient Indian religious, legal

and ritual code which determined the duties of every Hindu in keeping with

the tenets of Brahmanism. The compilation of these laws is traditionally

attributed to Manu, the mythical progenitor of man. Marx quotes from Manava

Dharma Sastra, or the Institutes of Manu According to the Gloss of Kulluka,

Comprising the Indian System of Duties, Religious and Civil, third edition,

Madras, 1863, p. 281. — <em>Ed</em>.] Chapter X, § 62.</p>

<p class="indentb">“Desertion of life, without reward, for the sake of preserving a priest or a cow ... may cause the beatitude of those base-born tribes.”</p>

<p class="fst">Naturally, it is impossible to deliver a five-year-old animal

before the lapse of five years. But what is possible, within certain limits,

is getting animals ready for their destination in less time by changing

the way of treating them. This is precisely what Bakewell accomplished.

Formerly English sheep, like the French as late as 1855, were not fit for

the butcher until four or five years old. According to the Bakewell system,

sheep may be fattened when only one year old and in every case have reached

their full growth before the end of the second year. By careful selection,

Bakewell, a Dishley Grange farmer, reduced the skeleton of sheep to the

minimum required for their existence. His sheep are called the New Leicesters.</p>

<p class="indentb">“... the breeder can now sent three to market in the same space of time that it formerly took him to prepare one; and if they are not taller, they

are broader, rounder, and have a greater development in those parts which

give most flesh. Of bone, they have absolutely no greater amount than is

necessary to support them, and almost all their weight is pure meat.” (Lavergne,

<em>The Rural Economy of England, etc</em>., 1855, p. 20.)</p>

<p class="fst">The methods which shorten the working periods are applicable in

various branches of industry to a widely varying extent and do not eliminate

the time differences of the various working periods. To stick to our illustration,

the working period required for the building of a locomotive may be absolutely

shortened by the employment of new machine-tools. But if at the same time

the finished product turned out daily or weekly by a cotton-spinning mill

is still more rapidly increased by improved processes, then the working

period in machine-building, compared with that in spinning, has nevertheless

grown relatively in length.

----

{{Das Kapital Volume Two Source Contribution}}

Show more