2016-02-29

Links to pdf of “Negative Interest Rate Policy as Conventional Monetary Policy” and to the abstract page on the National Institute Economic Review website. Thanks to the National Institute Economic Review for permission to post the full text of the paper here.

Abstract: As long as all interest rates move in tandem — including the rate of return on paper currency — economic theory suggests no important difference between interest rate changes in the positive region and interest rate changes in the negative region. Indeed, in standard models, only the real interest rate and spreads between real interest rates matter. Thus, in most respects, negative interest rate policy is conventional. It is only (a) what needs to be done with paper currency, (b) difficulties in understanding negative rates or © institutional features interacting with negative rates that make negative interest rate policy unconventional.

Keywords: monetary policy; negative interest rates; unconventional; stabilisation; transmission JEL Classifications: E52; E58; E42; E43; E41; E31

Miles Kimball is Professor of Economics and Survey Research at the University of Michigan, a Quartz Columnist and Independent Blogger on Economics, Politics and Religion
E-mail: zxkimball@gmail.com; Blog: http://blog.supplysideliberal.com. Along with coauthors, I have several academic papers on negative interest rate policy
in the works. In particular, this paper builds on Agarwal and Kimball (2015).

******************************************************************

It took a long time within mathematics for negative numbers to be fully accepted. To this day, negative numbers seem exotic to many people. So it will take a while for people to fully understand negative interest rates. But economic theory makes surprisingly little distinction between positive and negative rates. And the sophisticated business people and financiers who are key to the most important effects of interest rates will grasp the essentials of negative interest rates quickly. [1] Therefore, let me argue on both theoretical grounds and by spelling out some of the practical details that negative interest rate policy will turn out to be a more conventional type of monetary policy than people now realise.

In standard economic models, nominal interest rates don’t matter: only real interest rates and the spreads between them matter. The one seeming exception is not an exception at all: the opportunity cost of holding paper currency is closely related to the spread between the real interest rate on, say checking accounts, and the real interest rate on paper currency. Sometimes this equals the nominal interest rate because it has been traditional to have a zero nominal interest rate on paper currency, but it matters in the model because it is the spread between two real interest rates.

This essay is about how best to break with that restrictive tradition and engineer nonzero interest rates on paper currency when needed for economic stabilisation. If central banks take control over the paper currency interest rate, then it is possible to get paper currency out of the way of targeting any real interest rate — even deep negative rates — if necessary for economic stabilisation. But the principles of economic stabilisation and the monetary policy tools needed to achieve it — other than getting paper currency out of the way — are exactly the same as conventional monetary policy before the era of large-scale long-term asset purchases.

Building on Willem Buiter and Nikolaos Panigirtzoglou (2001, 2003) and Buiter (2004, 2007, 2009a,b,c) I have tried to figure out how to free up the paper currency interest rate in a way that is as close as possible to the current system in an effort to minimise the political cost to a central bank of getting paper currency out of the way of interest rate policy. I have taken the resulting specific proposal to on the whole receptive audiences at central banks around the world (listed in updated versions of Kimball, 2013a), and have made efforts to explain such a negative interest rate policy to the general public by blog posts on my blog ‘Confessions of a Supply-Side Liberal’, articles in online magazines such as Quartz and Slate, and by explaining negative interest rate policy to journalists. The blog posts and online magazine articles have included a children’s story (together with amateur rap, operatic, and read- aloud videos dramatising the story), an account of a conversation with my non-economist neighbour about negative interest rates, a quiz, and questions-and-answer posts answering such questions as “Is Electronic Money the Mark of the Beast?”. A regularly updated set of links to all of this material can be found in my regularly updated bibliographic post, ‘How and Why to Eliminate the Zero Lower Bound: A Reader’s Guide’ (Kimball 2013b). Along with coauthors, I have several academic papers on negative interest rate policy in the works.

There have been at least five recent milestones for negative interest rate policy as a real-world policy tool:

The current mild negative interest rates in the euro zone, Switzerland, Denmark and Sweden (see, for example, Randow, 2015).

The boldly titled 18 May, 2015 London conference on ‘Removing the Zero Lower Bound on Interest Rates’, cosponsored by Imperial College Business School, the Brevan Howard Centre for Financial Analysis, the Centre for Economic Policy Research and the Swiss National Bank.

The 19 May, 2015 Chief Economist’s Workshop at the Bank of England, which included keynote speeches by Ken Rogoff, presenting ‘Costs and Benefits to Phasing Out Paper Currency’ (Rogoff, 2014) and my presentation ‘18 Misconceptions about Eliminating the Zero Lower Bound’ (Kimball, 2015). Ken Rogoff’s paper is also scheduled to be the keynote presentation at the 19–20 November Bank of Canada Conference on Electronic Money and Payments.

Bank of England Chief Economist Andrew Haldane’s 18 September, 2015 speech, ‘How low can you go?’ (Haldane, 2015).

Ben Bernanke’s discussion of negative interest rate policy on his book tour (for Bernanke, 2015), ably reported by journalist Greg Robb in his Market Watch article ‘Fed officials seem ready to deploy negative rates in next crisis’ (Robb, 2015).

I want to emphasise that I consider the policy I am proposing as a realistic policy option that could be implemented at any point by central banks that have had it under active consideration and so have done the necessary staff work, and within a matter of weeks if necessary by central banks that have been caught flat- footed by a crisis without yet having done any of the staff work to prepare.

The remainder of this essay has three parts: first, explaining some of the details of my proposal to engineer a nonzero paper currency interest rate and thereby eliminate the lower bound; second, pointing out all of the aspects of monetary policy that would be unchanged by getting paper currency out of the way; and third, discussing the politics of negative interest rate policy.

How to engineer a nonzero paper currency interest rate in a way that is at minimum distance from the current system

My goal in policy design has been to find the paper currency policy closest to the current system that fully removes any zero lower bound. If I have not succeeded, I welcome any suggestions of how to find an alternative closer to the current monetary system, provided it allows short-term interest rates to go as low as needed to revive an economy, without the help of other stimulative policies, even after a shock significantly larger than the one that threw the world economy into the Great Recession, and regardless of how low inflation is.

In addition to looking for a system close to the current monetary system in order to minimise the political costs for a central bank implementing the policy I suggest, another reason to look at options close to the current system is to help bring the policy within the current legal authority of many central banks. Thinking of monetary politics in the United States, I am alert to the question of what could be done by the Federal Reserve System with the support of only the Executive Branch and a blocking coalition in Congress – a situation that would preclude any new enabling legislation. I cannot fully address all the legal questions here. The answer to many legal questions about the authority of the Fed are simply unknown, particularly since the more serious a future crisis, the more a court is likely to defer to the Fed’s judgment. And detailing the legal authority of all the central banks that might be interested in engineering a nonzero paper currency interest rate would be a large task indeed. It is my understanding that a number of central banks have significantly more legal leeway than the Fed to act on their own authority.

In 1932, Robert Eisler anticipated the essential element of the policy I am advocating (and that Willem Buiter and Nikolaos Panigirtzoglou discuss): a time-varying exchange rate between paper currency and money in the bank. Nowadays, money in the bank is a number in a computer, so I refer to it as ‘electronic money’. [2]

In this sense of electronic money, most US residents use electronic dollars almost every day when they pay for things by credit card, debit card, cheque or electronic funds transfer. In his 18 September speech (Haldane, 2015), Andrew Haldane advocates extending official government-sponsored electronic money from reserve accounts at the central bank and government-run payment clearing systems to government-sponsored electronic accounts that any household or firm could use. Although this would be helpful in furthering an electronic money policy, I do not think it is necessary. High-powered electronic money in reserve accounts and in the payment clearing system, plus electronic money in government-insured bank accounts provides enough of a starting place to institute an electronic money policy of the sort I am advocating.

Central banks have the power to establish the relative prices of different forms of money under their jurisdiction, a fact which is missing from many current money and banking textbooks. Currently, the Federal Reserve System has fixed exchange rates between all of the different forms of money under its jurisdiction. Two $10 bills are worth one $20 bill because at its cash windows, the Federal Reserve System will give banks $10 bills in unlimited quantities in exchange for half the number of $20 bills, and conversely, the Federal Reserve System will give banks $20 bills in unlimited quantities in exchange for twice the number of $10 bills. It is this exchange rate between $10 bills and $20 bills at the cash windows of the Fed and not the numbers printed on the faces of the green pieces of paper that determines their relative values.

There is no reason to alter the exchange rate between $10 bills and $20 bills, but there is a reason to free up the exchange rate between an electronic dollar (e-$) and a paper dollar (p-$): eliminating the zero lower bound as an effective constraint. Unlike higher inflation while keeping the exchange rate between paper dollars and electronic dollars at par, a time-varying exchange rate between paper dollars and electronic dollars can generate extra ‘inflation’ relative to paper currency at those times — and only those times — when inflation relative to paper currency is needed, without generating extra inflation relative to electronic money.

The exchange rate between paper dollars and electronic dollars would move very gradually. Cutting paper interest rates 400 basis points to –4 per cent per year to match electronic interest rates of –4 per cent per year (both expressed in terms of electronic dollars) is quite a large cut in interest rates. But it corresponds to lowering the value of an electronic dollar by only 1 per cent over a 90-day period or so — about 1.1 basis points decline in the value of the paper dollar per day. In other words, p-$1000 worth e-$1000 on day one would be worth about e-$999.89 on day two. That 11 cent per day change in the value of 1000 paper dollars is slow enough that it would give people time to adapt.

The starting point for the policy I am advocating is to encourage economic actors to use the electronic dollar — or euro, yen, pound, peso, etc. — as the unit of account, and as the unit in which prices are expressed. (To fix ideas, from here on I will write about the ‘electronic dollar’, which should be read in each case as ‘the electronic dollar — or euro, yen, pound, peso, etc.’). It is not essential that all prices be expressed in terms of the electronic dollar, but it is important that prices for a significant fraction of expenditure be expressed in terms of the electronic dollar, and the electronic money system will work most smoothly if all but a small fraction of prices are expressed in terms of electronic dollars. The idea is that purchases paid for by credit card, debit card, cheque, or electronic funds transfer would look exactly like they do now, while for paper currency purchases, retailers would have the option of applying a storewide paper currency surcharge, assessed at checkout as sales taxes now are. If, however, vending machine items and a few convenience store items continue to have separately determined paper currency prices, that is fine.

Arguably, the US and many other countries already have an electronic unit of account and electronic unit of price quotation in the sense of this thought experiment: suppose the exchange rate between paper currency and electronic money departed from par, but the central bank and the rest of the government maintained a studied neutrality about what the unit of account should be (including somehow making the two accounting systems equivalent as far as taxes go). I would bet that businesses would choose to do their accounting and their business-to-business transactions in terms of the electronic dollar instead of doing their accounting and business-to-business transactions in terms of the paper dollar. It is even more likely that electronic money would be the unit of account if, say, the announced policy of the central bank and the executive branch of the government was to favour the electronic dollar as much as existing legislation allowed. And if the electronic dollar were the unit of account in this sense, it is likely that it would also be the unit of price quotation at least for those retailers selling goods that are now mostly purchased with credit cards, debit cards, cheques or electronic funds transfers.

My view is that governments are big enough actors in the economy and in declaring focal points in multiple equilibrium situations (as the government does for Daylight Savings Time) that governments generally have control over what the unit of account is within their jurisdictions, except when there is an extremely high inflation rate or a history still burned into people’s memory of an extremely high inflation rate in that unit of account. Even nations that do lose control of their units of account are often able to partially restore that control with a newly created unit of account if policies are put in place to keep inflation rates in that new unit of account lower. And to the extent that prices in post- hyper-inflationary economies are still quoted in other units of account, it is usually associated with inflation that, while lower, is still high enough that the economy is far away from the zero lower bound. Here it is worth noting that the perception of extra inflation from paper currency’s depreciation itself is extra inflation relative to paper currency, which in any case the central bank is trying to make look unattractive as a unit of account. Electronic money is the hard money and paper currency is the soft money in this system. Thus, I think it likely that most governments could successfully declare an electronic unit of account, even when many people think of the status quo ante as a paper unit of account. To the extent that the electronic money policy is backed by the central bank and the executive branch while legislation is locked in place by legislative blocking coalitions in both directions – or by an unwillingness of the government to impose too high a political cost on members of parliament by an explicit parliamentary vote – I suspect that central bank and executive branch action alone is enough to establish an electronic unit of account.

What is a little trickier is the extent to which government control of the unit of account translates into control over the unit of price quotation. Actually, the key issue is the even more subtle one of whether current inflation inertia is carried over to electronic dollar prices or to paper dollar prices. During periods when the zero lower bound would otherwise be binding, I propose to have the value of a paper dollar in terms of electronic dollars fall very gradually according to a crawling peg exchange rate. If inflation inertia carries over to electronic goods prices, then the decline in the value of paper currency relative to electronic money can loosen the zero lower bound as much as needed, thus eliminating the zero lower bound as an effective constraint.

At the opposite extreme, if inflation inertia carries over in full to paper dollar prices, then the appreciation of the electronic dollar relative to the paper dollar implied by the depreciation of paper currency does nothing to loosen the zero lower bound.

If inflation inertia is carried over to some weighted
average of the electronic dollar prices and paper dollar
prices, there would be loosening of the zero lower bound.
If the weights in the weighted average are relatively
invariant, then it would still be possible to loosen the
zero lower bound as much as needed (thus eliminating
it as a binding constraint), though there would be a side
effect of a short-run drift in the relative prices of goods
and services priced in paper dollars relative to goods and
services priced in electronic dollars.

I consider this mixed case most likely in the initial
stages of putting into action a nonpar exchange rate
between paper currency and electronic money – for an
interesting reason. Under the current system, both paper
currency payments and debit and credit card payments
of different types are all accepted at face value at most
retailers that accept more than one form of payment.
Thus, it is likely that up to several per cent away from
par in the exchange rate between the paper dollar and
the electronic dollar, both electronic and paper prices
would be set at the same number in relation to face
values. In that case, it is likely that the unit of account
would dominate price setting for this unified face value
price. If so, that effectively makes inflation inertia
carry over to the electronic dollar prices, and makes
paper dollar prices effectively cheaper relative to those
electronic prices than the way they would compare
now – though in this initial period of time only within
the band in which some customers choose to pay in
paper while other customers choose to pay in electronic
form: by credit card, debit card or cheque.

In terms of the effectiveness of interest rate policy,
having both electronic dollar prices and face value paper
dollar prices carry over the preexisting level of inflation
inertia is fine at first. The most important transmission
mechanisms are through the cost of purchasing durables
and investment goods and international capital flows, all
of which involve goods most likely to be purchased with
electronic means of payments – by credit card, debit
card, cheque or electronic funds transfer – and therefore most likely to have a price set in electronic dollars. (Note
that many popular monetary policy models exclude this
entire list of key transmission mechanisms for monetary
policy by having only nondurable goods in a closed
economy.)

In this section, I have emphasised the messy case. My
claim is that it is very hard to come up with a plausible
scenario in which depreciating the paper dollar relative
to the electronic dollar at a sedate pace that creates a
negative rate of return for paper currency (with the rate
of return expressed in terms of electronic dollars) would
not provide leeway vis à vis the zero lower bound. It is
not plausible that all prices would be quoted primarily in
paper dollars with inflation inertia carrying over to these
pervasive paper dollar prices. It is simply too natural to
set an electronic dollar price for one’s goods if one is a
retailer selling predominantly goods purchased almost
entirely by credit card, debit card, cheque or electronic
funds transfer. And goods in this category are particularly
important for the monetary transmission mechanism.

A great advantage of depreciating the paper dollar
relative to the electronic dollar as compared to a policy
of keeping paper at par but raising the inflation rate is
that to provide leeway relative to the zero lower bound,
the paper dollar only needs to depreciate gradually (say
at 1.1 basis points per day) in periods when the central
bank’s target rate is negative. When the central bank’s
target rate is positive, the process can be reversed, with
the paper dollar very gradually appreciating back up to
par. By contrast, if one insists on keeping paper at par
and raising inflation to provide leeway vis à vis the zero
lower bound, it is not easy to bring inflation back down
after one no longer needs higher inflation to provide
leeway vis à vis the zero lower bound.

What remains the same about monetary
policy

I propose changing one thing: instead of always treating
the value of one paper dollar as equal to the value of
one electronic dollar, the central bank should sometimes
instruct the personnel at the cash window to treat the
value of one paper dollar as less than one electronic
dollar. This exchange rate at the cash window should
change very gradually in order to create a safe nonzero
rate of return for paper currency. By ‘safe’ return I mean
a return that is safe in the short-term sense in which
investing in the overnight fed funds market or the
overnight repo market is safe. It is not necessary that this
‘safe’ overnight rate be perfectly predictable in the more
distant future, any more than it is essential for monetary policy that the fed funds rate or the overnight repo rate
in the more distant future be perfectly predictable.

Everything else about monetary policy can continue in a
way very similar to the way things are done now. As under
the current system, the interest rate on reserves should be
lowered when the target rate is lowered. Also, as under
the current system (at least for the US), the interest rate
used in the tax system for money carried over between
tax years should be lowered along with other interest
rates (see Kimball and Kimball, 2015). Optionally, the
central bank’s lending rate (discount rate in the US) can
be lowered along with these other rates. When the target
rate is raised, these other rates can be raised as well. The
essential new feature of an ‘electronic money’ system is
that when the target rate goes below zero, the effective rate
of return for paper currency – the ‘paper currency interest
rate’ – also goes below zero through the depreciation
mechanism. And when the target rate goes above zero
again, the paper currency interest also becomes positive
through gradual appreciation of paper currency relative to
electronic money, until paper currency reaches par again.

The one change of having a gradually changing nonpar
exchange rate between the paper dollar and electronic
dollar may affect the transmission mechanism for those
goods and services that are purchased with cash, but
the parts of the transmission mechanism from interest
rate policy that work through goods and services that
are purchased with credit cards, debit cards, cheques
or electronic funds transfers remains. That includes
most durable goods purchases, most investment goods
purchases, and a large fraction of business-to-business
purchases. In addition, because international capital
flows and other asset market transactions are mostly
handled in electronic form, the parts of the transmission
mechanism from interest rate policy that involve the
international exchange rate and wealth effects remain
intact. That is more than enough to provide any needed
level of aggregate demand by a large enough change
in the target rate, with an accompanying adjustment
in the paper currency interest rate, and accompanying
adjustments in interest on reserves, the central bank’s
lending rate, the interest rate for the tax system, and any
other government interest rates fixed by government
policy that private agents can avail themselves of in a
more or less unlimited way (such as the postal savings
rate in Japan).

Except for the paper currency interest rate, many nations
already make all of these other rates comove closely
with the central bank’s target rate. Having a nonzero
‘paper currency interest rate’ that can comove closely when desired with the central bank’s target rate is the new
feature in an electronic money system. The nonzero ‘paper
currency interest rate’ needed for such comovement is
generated by gradual depreciation or appreciation of the
paper dollar relative to the electronic dollar.

As far as I know, very few economists have objected
to permanently raising the inflation rate as a way to
deal with the zero lower bound on the basis that this
would not, in fact, allow any extra monetary stimulus.
The reason is the fact I started with: standard models
say it is the real interest rate that matters. But if it is
the real interest rate that matters, lowering the nominal
interest rate without raising inflation will stimulate the
economy through totally standard mechanisms. It is not
necessary to have full agreement on exactly how a lower
real interest rate stimulates the economy. For all of those
who agree that interest rate policy matters, a cut in the
nominal interest rate will have much the same effect as
an increase in inflation with the nominal interest rate
held fixed. So if an increase in inflation operates through
conventional means, so does a cut into negative territory
of the full set of nominal government interest rates –
target rate, interest on reserves, lending rate, between-
tax-year rate, postal savings rate and paper currency
interest rate. In that sense, a negative interest rate policy
is a conventional monetary policy if having a target
inflation rate of 2 per cent or 4 per cent instead of a
target inflation rate of zero is a conventional monetary
policy. Having a nonzero paper currency interest rate
may be a little exotic, but that is only getting paper
currency out of the way. Once paper currency is out
of the way, the heart of negative interest rate policy is
lowering the target rate, which can by done by open
market purchases of short-term Treasury bills, the most
conventional of all tools.

It is worth noting that short-term Treasury bills are quite
useful in explaining negative interest rates and the zero
lower bound. Since a three-month Treasury bill only has
a payment at the end of the three months, a negative
interest rate for a three-month Treasury bill is simply
a price for the Treasury bill above the face value that
will be paid in three months. If one has to pay a higher
nominal price than what one gets three months later, the
nominal value of one’s money shrinks over those three
months. The zero lower bound can then be expressed
as the fact that (ignoring paper currency storage costs)
few people would pay, say $10,100 for a Treasury bill
with a face value of $10,000 to be paid in three months
when one can obtain $10,000 three months from now
for $10,000 now simply by storing the $10,000 in paper
currency for those three months.

The difference in an electronic money system is that in
this situation it would take paper currency with a face
value of $10,100 to be worth $10,000 in electronic
money three months from now. Even though what was
initially $10,100 worth of paper currency would still
have a face value of $10,100 three months from now,
the exchange rate at the cash window of the central bank
would make it worth less than its face value – not just
because it could only be deposited for that amount, but
also because anyone able to use the cash window of the
central bank could withdraw $10,100 face value worth
of paper currency at a cost of $10,000 in electronic
money three months from now.

Cutting interest rates within the negative range is
likely to have some effects on financial stability just as
cutting rates within the positive range. (I can see two
important differences: the side effects on the expected
rate of repayment until traditional debt contracts adjust
and the effect of the crumbling of the zero lower bound
on financial market worries about ‘secular stagnation’.)
In any case, the policy prescription I would offer is the
same: a dramatic increase in equity requirements for
financial firms and in equity requirements for individual
mortgages through mortgage reform that leads to
investors other than the homeowner putting up some
of the equity for a mortgage. Financial firms will resist
the loss of their implicit bailout subsidy, but from a
social point of view, the only important downside to
higher equity requirements is through aggregate demand
effects. But when central banks become comfortable
with negative interest rate policy, that can provide more
than enough aggregate demand; since interest rates can
go as low as needed, aggregate demand will no longer
be scarce. Thus, negative interest rate policy and high
equity requirements are highly complementary policies:
the negative interest rates easily provide the aggregate
demand that might be impaired somewhat by higher
equity requirements, while the dramatically higher
equity requirements provide in abundance the financial
stability that might be somewhat impaired by negative
interest rates.

Through experience, I know there are three aspects of
this system that at first can be hard to wrap one’s head
around. First, for some people, it seems very unnatural
to take the electronic dollar as numéraire rather than the
paper dollar. A numéraire is not the same thing as a unit
of account: a numéraire serves as the yardstick only for
a particular piece of economic analysis; a unit of account
serves as the yardstick for real world accounting and
transactions. I discussed issues involving the real-world
unit of account at length above. If everyone is thinking correctly, changing the numéraire one uses to think about
an electronic money system cannot change the implied
real-world bottom line. However, while equivalent,
the story ends up sounding much more complex if one
insists on using the paper dollar as numéraire. Making
the same analysis as above, but expressing it in terms of
a paper dollar numéraire, the carrying over of inflation
expectations to electronic dollar prices means that the
inflation rate for electronic dollar prices – expressed in
terms of paper dollars – goes up when the electronic dollar
is made to appreciate gradually relative to the paper dollar
by how electronic dollars are treated at the cash window
of the central bank. Then the anchoring of inflation
expectations for electronic dollar prices means that the
inflation rate for electronic dollar prices – expressed in
terms of paper dollars – can be brought down by making
the electronic dollar depreciate gradually back to par with
the paper dollar. Once the electronic dollar is back at par,
leaving it there makes the inflation rate for both paper
dollar and electronic dollar prices – as converted into
paper dollar prices – again the same.

Second, it is hard for many to see how it is possible to
avoid a financial arbitrage opportunity that subverts the
system – akin to the opportunity to save in paper currency
that creates the zero lower bound in the current system.
By construction, if the rate of return on paper currency is
always equal to the target rate, there can be no arbitrage
relative to the target rate. Then, leaving aside storage
costs, exactly the same thing would happen to the
value of one’s funds in the fed funds market or the repo
market as if one’s funds were entirely in paper currency.
How can that be, when the paper currency continues
to have the same face value, while electronic account
statements are showing lower and lower numbers due to
negative interest rates? The answer is that while interest
rates are negative, or when paper is below par after a
negative interest rate episode, the number of electronic
dollars each paper dollar is worth is varied to keep the
value of a pile of paper dollars equal to exactly what
one would have if one kept the money in the fed funds
market or the repo market. This is possible because an
initial value for the exchange rate between paper dollars
and electronic dollars, plus a stipulation that the rate
of return for paper currency expressed in terms of an
electronic dollar numéraire equal the target rate, yields
a differential equation that implies an equivalent value
for funds subject to compound interest in an electronic
account and funds in paper currency subject to a time-varying exchange rate when their value is converted into
an electronic dollar equivalent. And that equivalent value
of the paper currency is not a fiction; it is exactly what
the central bank would give for that amount of paper currency deposited at the cash window, and exactly the
price in electronic dollars the central bank would ask for
a withdrawal of that amount of paper currency. Keeping
the rate of return for paper currency equal to the target
rate while away from par leaves no degrees of freedom
in the path away from and back to par. There is only one
way to do it. But there is a sedate path for the exchange
rate that does it.

Third, many people think that an electronic money
system requires a change in what is ‘legal tender’.
This is a misunderstanding of what ‘legal tender’
means. Once paper currency is long established, most
countries do not feel the need to require that retailers
accept paper currency. ‘Legal tender’ can have the
much more limited meaning that paper currency can
be used to settle debts at face value. But one does not
have a ‘debt’ to a retailer until the retailer has agreed
to sell a good, and the retailer can refuse to sell a good
for an inconvenient means of payment, including paper
currency if that is inconvenient. Indeed, I have been on
more than one plane flight in which the crew clearly
announced that they would only accept credit or debit
card payment – not paper currency – for the food they
were selling on the flight. In US law, ‘legal tender’ also
means that, in theory, one can pay the government with
paper currency. But there are many cases in which it
would not, in practice, be easy at all to pay in paper
currency. Try telling the tax authority that you would
like to pay your income taxes in paper currency. You
might ultimately be able to force them to accept the
paper currency, but you would have a long and arduous
battle before you succeeded. The reason that the ability
to pay off debts in paper currency is a very real option
is that it is the creditor that must take a debtor to
court to enforce payment of a debt. So in the case of
a debt, it is the creditor that pays the costs of pursuit.
By contrast, at a minimum, even should the law be on
his or her side, anyone trying to insist on a right to pay
a resistant retailer or a resistant government agency in
paper currency would pay the costs of pursuit.

The right of private agents to pay off a debt in paper
currency may create an undesirable side effect of a
below-par value of paper currency, but it does not create
a zero lower bound. It doesn’t create a zero lower bound,
because the right to pay off debt in below-par paper
currency is limited to the value of one’s debts – and
indeed only to the value of the payments one is able to
make on one’s debts (including any prepayment option)
during the time paper currency is below par. It is not an
unlimited arbitrage. Analytically, if one ignored extra
paper currency handling costs and assumed that all debt payments during the time paper currency was below par
were made in paper currency, everyone who had debts
would be at a corner solution, unable to pay off more
debt in paper currency because every possible way to
do so was already exhausted. The option to prepay an
entire mortgage in paper currency is definitely big enough
to be interesting, but the importance of the prepayment
option for mortgages during times of declining interest
rates is already so great that we know the system does
not break down simply because of a flood of mortgage
refinancings. In the overall scheme of things, adding a few
per cent to the benefit of refinancing because of the option
to pay off the mortgage with below-par paper currency is
a modest wrinkle on the large benefits to refinancing that
could arise simply because of the likely mortgage interest
rate changes that would be engendered by the temporary
negative interest rate policy.

Similarly, if the tax authority did have to accept payments
in below-par paper currency, this would be an effective
reduction in the tax rate, and an undesirable side effect
also because of socially wasteful paper currency handling
costs, but it would not create a zero lower bound. Once
someone had paid all his or her taxes in paper currency,
the opportunity would be exhausted.

The politics of negative interest rates

Although the economics of cutting interest rates in
negative territory are essentially the same as the economics
of cutting interest rates in positive territory with a higher
inflation rate, with a few wrinkles from what it takes to
get paper currency out of the way, the politics of negative
interest rates could be quite different from the politics of
positive interest rates. One should not go overboard in
saying this, however, since we now know that the mild
negative interest rates in the euro zone, Switzerland,
Denmark and Sweden have not unleashed a firestorm of
political protest. To compare distinct events just to get
an idea of political magnitudes, at the moment, people
in the euro zone, Denmark and Sweden are much more
concerned about the flood of refugees from the Middle
East than they are incensed about central banks daring
to have a nominal interest rate below zero. And in the
past few years, the referendum that could have tied the
Swiss National Bank’s hands was one meant to keep the
Swiss National Bank from piling up too large a stock
of foreign assets, not a referendum to prevent it from
imposing negative interest rates.

Many of the people who argue most strenuously against
negative interest rates are likely to be the same people who
tend to argue for higher target rates and tighter monetary
policy in other dimensions in almost every situation. However, monetary ‘hawks’ in this sense might be able
to get regular people more concerned about cutting
interest rates into the negative region than a similar cut
in interest rates in the positive region – even if different
inflation rates in the two situations made the economics
essentially equivalent.

There are some basic arguments that can be used to
defend negative interest rate policy. The first – and
perhaps the most important – is to explain to people
repeatedly, ideally long in advance of when negative
interest rates are actually needed, that the economics of
negative interest rate policy are entirely conventional,
except for a few details about how paper currency
would be handled.

Second, it is worth saying over and over again that even
for savers, deep negative interest rates for a short time
during a serious recession, bringing speedy economic
recovery, are better than zero nominal rates that are 2 per
cent below inflation for years and years, accompanied by
a lagging economy for that longer time.

Third, the focus on savers, while deeply entrenched
in political thought, should be put into perspective by
pointing out the benefits of negative interest rates to
borrowers.

Fourth, it should be noted that – except when the
new policy looked like the current system – people
who use paper currency would be earning the same
effective interest rate as people who kept their money in
electronic accounts, and so would not be treated unfairly.
Moreover, the fact that paper currency would earn the
same as money in electronic accounts would mean that
there would be no incentive to underuse paper currency.

Fifth, it may be useful to point out that the central bank
can easily subsidise the provision of zero interest rates
to small checking and saving accounts by tying such
provision to the amount of a bank’s reserves that is
exempted from negative interest rates. (In addition to
reducing political costs by encouraging banks to shield
small accounts from negative interest rates, this can
avoid undesirable effects on financial stability or bank
lending from the strain on banks’ profits and balance
sheets that might result from banks choosing to shield
small accounts from negative rates for customer relations
reasons despite the absence of any subsidy.)

Sixth, many of those who argue for higher interest rates
also want lower inflation. With the zero lower bound
vanquished, the target rate for inflation can be lowered, since inflation in the electronic unit of account is not
necessary in order to steer away from the zero lower
bound.

Also, for countries that, for good or ill, rely in an
important way on seignorage revenue, seignorage
revenue can be obtained by a paper currency interest
rate below the target rate, regardless of the inflation rate
in the electronic unit of account. Thus, inflation in the
unit of account is not necessary for seignorage, removing
one temptation towards higher inflation.

In the context of discussing seignorage, it may be worth
trying to insist that a negative paper currency interest
rate is not a tax if it simply equals the target rate. It is
only a paper currency interest rate below the target rate
that is a tax. Though we are used to it, a zero paper
currency interest rate is a tax if the target rate is positive;
but a negative paper currency interest rate is not a tax if
the target rate is equally negative.

Seventh, the possibility of deep negative interest rates
means that aggregate demand is no longer scarce. Thus
– except perhaps for the nine-month or so lag before
monetary policy takes hold – there is no need for any
other means of affecting aggregate demand. With
negative interest rates in play, fiscal policy can focus on
the long run and getting good deals for taxpayers rather
than aggregate demand stimulus. That in turn removes
one important force leading to higher national debt.
The possibility of deep negative interest rates makes
quantitative easing unnecessary for aggregate demand
management. And the possibility of negative interest
rates means that many other things that people justify in
part because they add to aggregate demand must stand on
other merits, aside from any effects on aggregate demand.

Finally, the benefits of economic stabilisation should be
emphasised. The Great Recession was no picnic. Deep
negative interest rates throughout 2009 – somewhere in
the –4 per cent to –7 per cent range – could have brought
robust recovery by early to mid 2010. The output gaps
the world suffered in later years were all part of the cost
of the zero lower bound. These output gaps not only
had large direct costs, they also distracted policymakers
from attending to other important issues. For example,
the later part of the Great Recession that could have
been avoided by negative interest rate policy led to a
relatively sterile debate in Europe between fiscal stimulus
and austerity, with supply-side reform getting relatively
little attention. And the later part of the Great Recession
that could have been avoided by negative interest rate
policy brought down many governments for whom the political benefits of negative interest rate policy would
have been immense. And for central banks, it looks good
to get the job done.

Footnotes

[1]

As Ruchir Agarwal and I paraphrased in Agarwal and Kimball
(2015), “Preliminary evidence for the pass-through and demand
for cash at negative interest rates comes from Denmark
(Danmarks Nationalbank, 2015). Since Feb 6, 2015 Danmarks
Nationalbank’s rate of interest on certificates of deposit has
been –0.75 per cent. The interest rate on certificate of deposits
was lowered into negative territory to defend the Danish fixed
exchange rate policy under which monetary policy rates are set
solely to maintain a fixed exchange rate of the krone against
the euro. The Danmarks Nationalbank study finds that the
negative interest rates have not weakened the pass-through from
Danmarks Nationalbank’s interest rates to money market rates.
Moreover, consistent with the discussion above, they find that
the negative interest rates have not been fully passed through to
bank deposit and lending rates to households. However, large
deposits from firms and institutional investors are extensively
paying negative interest rates. Lastly, they find no evidence of any
substantial change at the current level of interest rates in the way
banknotes and coins (currency) in circulation are being used.”

[2]

The overtones of Bitcoin and its ilk in the phrase “electronic
money” are a mostly unfortunate distraction analytically, but
are a plus in popularising this proposal for eliminating the zero
lower bound.

References

Agarwal, R. and Kimball, M.S. (2015), ‘Breaking through the zero lower bound’, IMF Working Paper no. 15/224, available at http:// www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/longres.aspx?sk=43358.0.

Bernanke, B. (2015), The Courage to Act: A Memoir of a Crisis and its Aftermath, Norton.

Buiter, W.H. (2004), ‘Overcoming the zero bound: Gesell vs. Eisler; discussion of Mitsuhiro Fukao’s “The effects of ‘Gesell” (currency) taxes in promoting Japan’s economic recovery’, discussion presented at the Conference on Macro/Financial Issues and International Economic Relations: Policy Options for Japan and the United States, October 22–23, Ann Arbor, MI, USA. International Economics and Economic Policy, 2, Nos 2–3, November 2005, pp. 189–200. Publisher: Springer-Verlag GmbH; ISSN: 1612–4804 (Paper) 16124812 (Online).

— (2007), ‘Is numérairology the future of monetary economics? Unbundling numéraire and medium of exchange through a virtual currency with a shadow exchange rate’, Open Economies Review, Springer Netherlands; ISSN 0923–7992 (Print); 1573–708X (Online). Electronic publication date: Thursday, 3 May, 2007. See “Springer Website.”

— (2009a), ‘Negative interest rates: when are they coming to a central bank near you?’, ft.com/maverecon, 7 May.

— (2009b), ‘The wonderful world of negative nominal interest rates, again’, ft.com/maverecon, 19 May.

— (2009c), ‘Negative nominal interest rates: three ways to overcome the zero lower bound’, NBER Working Paper No. 15118. Buiter, W.H. and Panigirtzoglou, N. (2001), ‘Liquidity traps: how to avoid them and how to escape them’, in Vanthoor, W.F.V. and Mooij, J. (eds), Reflections on Economics and Econometrics, Essays in Honour of Martin Fase, De Nederlandsche Bank NV, Amsterdam, pp. 13–58.

— (2003), ‘Overcoming the zero bound on nominal interest rates with negative interest on currency: Gesell’s solution’, Economic Journal, 113 (490), October, pp. 723–46.

Danmarks Nationalbank (2015), Monetary Review, 2nd Quarter, Article 2.

Haldane, A.S. (2015), ‘How low can you go?’, speech given at the Portadown Chamber of Commerce, Northern Ireland, 18 September.

Kimball, C.E. and Kimball, M.S. (2015), ‘However low interest rates might go, the IRS will never act like a bank’, posted on Quartz, 15 April, available at http://qz.com/383737/however-low-interest- rates-might-go-the-irs-will-never-act-like-a-bank/.

Kimball, M.S. (2013a), ‘Electronic money: the powerpoint file’, originally posted 17 June 17 on the Tumblr blog “Confessions of a Supply-Side Liberal”, updated version accessible at  http://blog.supplysideliberal.com/post/53171609818/electronic-money-the- powerpoint-file.

— (2013b), ‘How and why to eliminate the zero lower bound: a reader’s guide’, originally posted 30 September on the Tumblr blog “Confessions of a Supply-Side Liberal”, updated version accessible at http://blog.supplysideliberal.com/post/62693219358/ how-and-why-to-eliminate-the-zero-lower-bound-a.

— (2015), ’18 misconceptions about eliminating the zero lower bound’, first presented 19 May at the Chief Economists’ Workshop at the Bank of England, updated Powerpoint file available at http://blog.supplysideliberal.com/post/119337047479/18- misconceptions-about-eliminating-the-zero-lower.

Randow, J. (2015), ‘Less than zero: when interest rates go negative’, Bloomberg View, updated 13 April, available at http://www. bloombergview.com/quicktake/negative-interest-rates.

Robb, G. (2015), ‘Fed officials seem ready to deploy negative rates in next crisis’, Market Watch, 12 October, available at http://www. marketwatch.com/story/fed-officials-seem-ready-to-deploy- negative-rates-in-next-crisis-2015–10–10.

Rogoff, K. (2014), ‘Costs and benefits to phasing out paper currency’, NBER Working Paper #20126.

Show more