2016-10-17



Culled—Proshare

16/10/2016/ Federal Reserve Chair Janet L. Yellen

60th Annual Economic Conference Sponsored By The Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Boston, Massachusetts, October 14, 2016, Macroeconomic Research After The Crisis

Extreme economic events have often challenged existing views of how the economy works and exposed shortcomings in the collective knowledge of economists. To give two well-known examples, both the Great Depression and the stagflation of the 1970s motivated new ways of thinking about economic phenomena. More recently, the financial crisis and its aftermath might well prove to be a similar sort of turning point.

Today I would like to reflect on some ways in which the events of the past few years have revealed limits in economists’ understanding of the economy and suggest several important questions I hope the profession will try to answer. Some of these questions are not new, though recent events have made them more urgent. Appropriately, some are addressed by the papers prepared for this conference.

Pursuing answers to these questions is vital to the work of Federal Reserve and other economic policymakers, and the Fed is likewise engaged in ongoing research to seek answers.

The Influence of Demand on Aggregate Supply

The first question I would like to pose concerns the distinction between aggregate supply and aggregate demand: Are there circumstances in which changes in aggregate demand can have an appreciable, persistent effect on aggregate supply?

Prior to the Great Recession, most economists would probably have answered this question with a qualified “no.” They would have broadly agreed with Robert Solow that economic output over the longer term is primarily driven by supply–the amount of output of goods and services the economy is capable of producing, given its labor and capital resources and existing technologies. Aggregate demand, in contrast, was seen as explaining shorter-term fluctuations around the mostly exogenous supply-determined longer-run trend.1This conclusion deserves to be reconsidered in light of the failure of the level of economic activity to return to its pre-recession trend in most advanced economies. This post-crisis experience suggests that changes in aggregate demand may have an appreciable, persistent effect on aggregate supply–that is, on potential output.2

The idea that persistent shortfalls in aggregate demand could adversely affect the supply side of the economy–an effect commonly referred to as hysteresis–is not new; for example, the possibility was discussed back in the mid-1980s with regard to the performance of European labor markets.3But interest in the topic has increased in light of the persistent slowdown in economic growth seen in many developed economies since the crisis. Several recent studies present cross-country evidence indicating that severe and persistent recessions have historically had these sorts of long-term effects, even for downturns that appear to have resulted largely or entirely from a shock to aggregate demand.4With regard to the U.S. experience, one study estimates that the level of potential output is now 7 percent below what would have been expected based on its pre-crisis trajectory, and it argues that much of this supply-side damage is attributable to several developments that likely occurred as a result of the deep recession and slow recovery.5

In particular, the study finds that in the wake of the crisis, the United States experienced a modest reduction in labor supply as a result of reduced immigration and a fall in labor force participation beyond what can be explained by cyclical conditions and demographic factors, as well as a marked slowdown in the estimated trend growth rate of labor productivity. The latter likely reflects an unusually slow pace of business capital accumulation since the crisis and, more conjecturally, the sharp decline in spending on research and development and the very slow pace of new firm formation in recent years.6

If we assume that hysteresis is in fact present to some degree after deep recessions, the natural next question is to ask whether it might be possible to reverse these adverse supply-side effects by temporarily running a “high-pressure economy,” with robust aggregate demand and a tight labor market. One can certainly identify plausible ways in which this might occur.

Increased business sales would almost certainly raise the productive capacity of the economy by encouraging additional capital spending, especially if accompanied by reduced uncertainty about future prospects. In addition, a tight labor market might draw in potential workers who would otherwise sit on the sidelines and encourage job-to-job transitions that could also lead to more-efficient–and, hence, more-productive–job matches.7Finally, albeit more speculatively, strong demand could potentially yield significant productivity gains by, among other things, prompting higher levels of research and development spending and increasing the incentives to start new, innovative businesses.

Hysteresis effects–and the possibility they might be reversed–could have important implications for the conduct of monetary and fiscal policy. For example, hysteresis would seem to make it even more important for policymakers to act quickly and aggressively in response to a recession, because doing so would help to reduce the depth and persistence of the downturn, thereby limiting the supply-side damage that might otherwise ensue. In addition, if strong economic conditions can partially reverse supply-side damage after it has occurred, then policymakers may want to aim at being more accommodative during recoveries than would be called for under the traditional view that supply is largely independent of demand.

More research is needed, however, to better understand the influence of movements in aggregate demand on aggregate supply.8From a policy perspective, we of course need to bear in mind that an accommodative monetary stance, if maintained too long, could have costs that exceed the benefits by increasing the risk of financial instability or undermining price stability. More generally, the benefits and potential costs of pursuing such a strategy remain hard to quantify, and other policies might be better suited to address damage to the supply side of the economy.

Heterogeneity

My second question asks whether individual differences within broad groups of actors in the economy can influence aggregate economic outcomes–in particular, what effect does such heterogeneity have on aggregate demand?

Many macroeconomists work with models where groups of individual actors, such as households or firms, are treated as a single “representative” agent whose behavior stands in for that of the group as a whole. For example, rather than explicitly modeling and then adding up the separate actions of a large number of different households, a macro model might instead assume that the behavior of a single “average” household can describe the aggregate behavior of all households.

Prior to the financial crisis, these so-called representative-agent models were the dominant paradigm for analyzing many macroeconomic questions. However, a disaggregated approach seems needed to understand some key aspects of the Great Recession. To give one example, consider the effects of negative housing equity on consumption. Although households typically reduce their spending in response to wealth declines, the many households whose equity positions in their homes were actually driven negative by the reduction in house prices may have curtailed their spending even more sharply because of a markedly reduced ability to borrow. Such a development, in turn, would shift the relationship between housing equity (which remained solidly positive in the aggregate) and consumer spending for the economy as a whole. Such a shift in an aggregate relationship would be difficult to understand or predict without using disaggregated data and models.

More generally, studying the effects of household and firm heterogeneity might help us better account for the severity of the recession and the slow recovery. At the household level, recent research finds that heterogeneity can amplify the effects of adverse shocks, a result that is largely driven by households with very little net worth that sharply increase their savings in a recession.9At the firm level, there is evidence that financial constraints had a particularly large adverse effect on employment at small firms and the start-up of new firms, factors that may be part of the explanation for the Great Recession’s long duration and the subsequent slow recovery.10More generally, if larger firms seeking to expand have better access to credit than smaller ones, overall growth in investment and employment could depend in part on the distribution of sales across different types of businesses. Modeling any of these issues quantitatively will likely require the use of a heterogeneous-agent framework.

Economists’ understanding of how changes in fiscal and monetary policy affect the economy might also benefit from the recognition that households and firms are heterogeneous. For example, in simple textbook models of the monetary transmission mechanism, central banks operate largely through the effect of real interest rates on consumption and investment. Once heterogeneity is taken into account, other important channels emerge. For example, spending by many households and firms appears to be quite sensitive to changes in labor income, business sales, or the value of collateral that in turn affects their access to credit–conditions that monetary policy affects only indirectly. Studying monetary models with heterogeneous agents more closely could help us shed new light on these aspects of the monetary transmission mechanism.

While the economics profession has long been aware that these issues matter, their effects had been incorporated into macro models only to a very limited extent prior to the financial crisis.11I am glad to now see a greater emphasis on the possible macroeconomic consequences of heterogeneity, including in work by economists at the Federal Reserve.12Nevertheless, the various linkages between heterogeneity and aggregate demand are not yet well understood, either empirically or theoretically. More broadly, even though the tools of monetary policy are generally not well suited to achieve distributional objectives, it is important for policymakers to understand and monitor the effects of macroeconomic developments on different groups within society.

Financial Linkages to the Real Economy

My third question concerns a key issue for monetary policy and macroeconomics that is less directly addressed by this conference: How does the financial sector interact with the broader economy?

In light of the housing bubble and subsequent events, policymakers clearly need to better understand what kinds of developments contribute to financial crises. What is the relationship between the buildup of excessive leverage and the value of real estate and other types of collateral, and what factors impede or facilitate the deleveraging process that follows? Does the economic fallout from a financial crisis depend on the particulars of the crisis, such as whether it involves widespread damage to household balance sheets? How does the nature and degree of the interconnections between financial firms affect the propagation and amplification of stress through the financial system and overall economy? Finally–and most importantly–what can monetary policy and financial oversight do to reduce the frequency and severity of future crises?

Although the scope of these questions extends beyond the themes of this conference, it does include issues that are closely related. Consider the influence of balance sheet conditions and noninterest credit terms on spending and overall activity–an area where it is important to take account of differences across individual households and firms, as I just noted. Research on this topic has, of course, been ongoing for some time, and it has expanded greatly in the wake of the financial crisis.13But I believe we have a lot more to learn about the ways in which changes in underwriting standards and other determinants of credit availability interact with interest rates to affect such things as consumer spending, housing demand and home prices, business investment (especially for small firms), and the formation of new firms.14

For example, is the persistent increase in the personal saving rate that we have observed since the collapse of the housing bubble primarily a result of a sustained shift toward more prudent underwriting standards by lenders? Is it something that will ultimately prove transitory once householdsfinish repairing their balance sheets or become more confident about their future prospects for employment and income?15The answer to thislatter question could have significant implications for the longer-run normal, or neutral, level of interest rates and thus for the conduct of monetary policy.

Inflation Dynamics

My fourth question goes to the heart of monetary policy: What determines inflation?

From my perspective, the standard framework for thinking about inflation dynamics used by central bank economists and others prior to the financial crisis remains conceptually useful today. A simple description of this framework might go something like this:16Inflation is characterized by an underlying trend that has been essentially constant since the mid-1990s; previously, this trend seemed to drift over time, influenced by actual past inflation or other economic conditions. Theory and evidence suggest that this trend is strongly influenced by inflation expectations that, in turn, depend on monetary policy. In particular, the remarkable stability of various measures of expected inflation in recent years presumably represents the fruits of the Federal Reserve’s sustained efforts since the early 1980s to bring down and then stabilize inflation at a low level. The anchoring of inflation expectations that has resulted from this policy does not, however, prevent actual inflation from fluctuating from year to year in response to the temporary influence of movements in energy prices and other disturbances. In addition, inflation will tend to run above or below its underlying trend to the extent that resource utilization–which may serve as an indicator of firms’ marginal costs–is persistently high or low.17

While this general framework for thinking about the inflation process remains useful, questions about some of its quantitative features have arisen in the wake of the Great Recession and the subsequent slow recovery. For example, the influence of labor market conditions on inflation in recent years seems to be weaker than had been commonly thought prior to the financial crisis. Although inflation fell during the recession, the decline was quite modest given how high unemployment rose; likewise, wages and prices rose comparatively little as the labor market gradually recovered. Whether this reduction in sensitivity was somehow caused by the recession or instead pre-dated it and was merely revealed under extreme conditions is unclear.18Either way, the underlying cause is unknown. Does the reduced sensitivity reflect structural changes, such as globalization or a greater role for intangible capital in production that have reduced the importance of cyclical swings in domestic activity for firms’ marginal costs and pricing power? Or does it perhaps reflect the well-documented reluctance–or, alternatively, limited ability–of firms to cut the nominal wages of their employees, which could help to explain the relatively moderate movements in inflation we saw during and after the recession?19

Another gap in our knowledge about the nature of the inflation process concerns expectations. Although many theoretical models suggest that actual inflation should be most closely related to short-run inflation expectations, as an empirical matter, measures of long-run expectations appear to explain the data better.20Yet another unresolved issue concerns whose expectations–those of consumers, firms, or investors–are most relevant for wage and price setting, a point on which theory provides no clear-cut guidance. More generally, the precise manner in which expectations influence inflation deserves further study.21

Perhaps most importantly, we need to know more about the manner in which inflation expectations are formed and how monetary policy influences them. Ultimately, both actual and expected inflation are tied to the central bank’s inflation target, whether that target is explicit or implicit.22But how does this anchoring process occur? Does a central bank have to keep actual inflation near the target rate for many years before inflation expectations completely conform? Can policymakers instead materially influence inflation expectations directly and quickly by simply announcing their intention to pursue a particular inflation goal in the future? Or does the truth lie somewhere in between, with a change in expectations requiring some combination of clear communications about policymakers’ inflation goal, concrete policy actions to demonstrate their commitment to that goal, and at least some success in moving actual inflation toward its desired level in order to demonstrate the feasibility of the strategy? Although historical experience suggests that changing the public’s inflation expectations would be neither quick nor easy, it is not clear which of these possibilities is correct.23

With nominal short-term interest rates at or close to their effective lower bound in many countries, the broader question of how expectations are formed has taken on heightened importance. Under such circumstances, many central banks have sought additional ways to stimulate their economies, including adopting policies that are directly aimed at influencing expectations of future interest rates and inflation. The unusually explicit and extended guidance about the likely future path of the federal funds rate that was provided by the FOMC from 2011 through 2014 is an example of such a policy, as is the Bank of Japan’s upward revision to its official inflation objective in 2013. Moreover, these and other expectational strategies may be needed again in the future, given the likelihood that the global economy may continue to experience historically low interest rates, thereby making it unlikely that reductions in short-term interest rates alone would be an adequate response to a future recession.24

For all of these reasons, I hope that researchers will strive to improve our understanding of inflation dynamics and its interactions with monetary policy.

International Linkages

Before closing, let me mention one additional area where more study is needed–the effects of changes in U.S. monetary policy on financial and economic conditions in the rest of the world and the ways in which those foreign effects can feed back to influence conditions here at home. Of course, cross-country monetary policy spillovers have been the subject of scholarly debate since the Great Depression, and much of the formal analysis of this topic dates back to the early 1960s.25But this issue has received renewed interest with the advent of unconventional monetary policies after the Great Recession and, more recently, the divergence of monetary policies among major advanced-economy central banks.

Broadly speaking, monetary policy actions in one country spill over to other economies through three main channels: changes in exchange rates; changes in domestic demand, which alter the economy’s imports; and changes in domestic financial conditions–such as interest rates and asset prices–that, through portfolio balance and other channels, affect financial conditions abroad. Research by Federal Reserve staff suggests that, all told, U.S. monetary policy spillovers to other economies are positive–that is, policies designed to provide stimulus to the U.S. economy also boost activity abroad, as negative effects of dollar depreciation are offset by positive effects of higher U.S. imports and easier foreign financial conditions.26

However, this issue is far from settled, as are a host of other related questions, including the following: Do U.S. monetary policy actions affect advanced and emerging market countries differently? Do conventional and unconventional monetary policies spill over to other countries differently? And to what extent are U.S. interest rates and financial conditions influenced by easing measures abroad?

Conclusion

In closing, I would like to commend the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston for organizing this conference and fostering research and debate on questions vital to our understanding of the economy. Answering these questions will help the Federal Reserve’s efforts to promote a healthy economy, and I am grateful for the opportunity to speak to you today and be part of this important discussion.

References

1.      Agnello, Luca, and Ludger Schuknecht (2011). “Booms and Busts in Housing Markets: Determinants and Implications,” Journal of Housing Economics, vol. 20 (September), pp. 171-90.

Akerlof, George A., William T. Dickens, and George L. Perry (1996). “The Macroeconomics of Low Inflation (PDF),” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 1, pp. 1-76.

Akerlof, George A., Andrew K. Rose, and Janet L. Yellen (1988). “Job Switching and Job Satisfaction in the U.S. Labor Market (PDF),” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 2, pp. 495-594.

Ammer, John, Michiel De Pooter, Christopher Erceg, and Steven Kamin (2016). “International Spillovers of Monetary Policy,” IFDP Notes. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, February 8.

Auclert, Adrien (2016). “Monetary Policy and the Redistribution Channel (PDF),” unpublished paper, Stanford University, Department of Economics, January.

Bernanke, Ben S., and Mark Gertler (1989). “Agency Costs, Net Worth, and Business Fluctuations,” American Economic Review, vol. 79 (March), pp. 14-31.

Bernanke, Ben S., Mark Gertler, and Simon Gilchrist (1999a). “The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business Cycle Framework,” in John B. Taylor and Michael Woodford, eds., Handbook of Macroeconomics, vol. 1C. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 1341-93.

Bernanke, Ben S., Thomas Laubach, Frederic S. Mishkin, and Adam S. Posen (1999b). Inflation Targeting: Lessons from the International Experience. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.

Blanchard, Olivier (2016). “The Phillips Curve: Back to the ’60s?” American Economic Review, vol. 106 (May), pp. 31-34.

Blanchard, Olivier, Eugenio Cerutti, and Lawrence Summers (2015). “Inflation and Activity–Two Explorations and Their Monetary Policy Implications (PDF),” IMF Working Paper WP/15/230. Washington: International Monetary Fund, November.

Blanchard, Olivier J., and Lawrence H. Summers (1986). “Hysteresis and the European Unemployment Problem,” in Stanley Fischer, ed., NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1986, vol. 1. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, pp. 15-90.

Blinder, Alan S., and Janet L. Yellen (2001). The Fabulous Decade: Macroeconomic Lessons from the 1990s. New York: Century Foundation Press.

Cerra, Valerie, and Sweta Chaman Saxena (2008). “Growth Dynamics: The Myth of Economic Recovery,” American Economic Review, vol. 98 (March), pp. 439-57.

Chaney, Thomas, David Sraer, and David Thesmar (2012). “The Collateral Channel: How Real Estate Shocks Affect Corporate Investment,” American Economic Review, vol. 102 (October), pp. 2381-409.

Chodorow-Reich, Gabriel (2014). “The Employment Effects of Credit Market Disruptions: Firm-Level Evidence from the 2008-9 Financial Crisis,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 129 (February), pp. 1-59.

Clark, Todd E., and Troy Davig (2008). “An Empirical Assessment of the Relationships among Inflation and Short- and Long-Term Expectations (PDF),” Research Working Paper RWP 08-05. Kansas City: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, November.

Clementi, Gian Luca, and Berardino Palazzo (2016). “Entry, Exit, Firm Dynamics, and Aggregate Fluctuations,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, vol. 8 (July), pp. 1-41.

Daly, Mary C., and Bart Hobijn (2014). “Downward Nominal Rigidities Bend the Phillips Curve,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 46 (October), pp. 51-93.

Del Negro, Marco, Marc P. Giannoni, and Frank Schorfheide (2015). “Inflation in the Great Recession and New Keynesian Models,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, vol. 7 (January), pp. 168-96.

Dokko, Jane, Brian M. Doyle, Michael T. Kiley, Jinill Kim, Shane Sherlund, Jae Sim, and Skander Van Den Heuvel (2011). “Monetary Policy and the Global Housing Bubble,” Economic Policy, vol. 26 (April), pp. 237-87.

Duygan-Bump, Burcu, Alexey Levkov, and Judit Montoriol-Garriga (2015). “Financing Constraints and Unemployment: Evidence from the Great Recession,” Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 75 (October), pp. 89-105.

Fair, Ray C. (2004). Estimating How the Macroeconomy Works. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.

Fallick, Bruce C., Michael Lettau, and William L. Wascher (2016). “Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity in the United States during and after the Great Recession (PDF),” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2016-001. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, January.

Faust, Jon, and Jonathan H. Wright (2013). “Forecasting Inflation,” in Graham Elliott and Allan Timmermann, eds., Handbook of Economic Forecasting, vol. 2A. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 3-56.

Fernald, John G. (2015). “Productivity and Potential Output before, during, and after the Great Recession,” in Jonathan A. Parker and Michael Woodford, eds., NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2014, vol. 29. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 1-51.

Fleming, J. Marcus (1962). “Domestic Financial Policies under Fixed and under Floating Exchange Rates,” International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, vol. 9 (November), pp. 369-80.

Fukuda, Yoshiyuki, Yuki Kimura, Nao Sudo, and Hiroshi Ugai (2013). “Cross-Country Transmission Effect of the U.S. Monetary Shock under Global Integration (PDF),” Bank of Japan Working Paper Series 13-E-16. Tokyo: BOJ, November.

Georgiadis, Georgios (2015). “Determinants of Global Spillovers from U.S. Monetary Policy (PDF),” ECB Working Paper Series 1854. Frankfurt am Main, Germany: European Central Bank, September.

Gertler, Mark, and Peter Karadi (2015). “Monetary Policy Surprises, Credit Costs, and Economic Activity,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, vol. 7 (January), pp. 44-76.

Glick, Reuven, and Sylvain Leduc (2015). “Unconventional Monetary Policy and the Dollar: Conventional Signs, Unconventional Magnitudes (PDF),” Working Paper Series 2015-18. San Francisco: Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, November.

Gordon, Robert J. (2013). “The Phillips Curve Is Alive and Well: Inflation and the NAIRU during the Slow Recovery (PDF),” NBER Working Paper Series 19390. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, August.

Gornemann, Nils, Keith Kuester, and Makoto Nakajima (2016). “Doves for the Rich, Hawks for the Poor? Distributional Consequences of Monetary Policy (PDF),” International Finance Discussion Papers 1167. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Gourio, Francois, Todd Messer, and Michael Siemer (2016). “Firm Entry and Macroeconomic Dynamics: A State-Level Analysis,” American Economic Review, vol. 106 (May), pp. 214-18.

Guvenen, Fatih (2011). “Macroeconomics with Heterogeneity: A Practical Guide (PDF),” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Economic Quarterly, vol. 97 (Third Quarter), pp. 255-326.

Holzer, Harry J., Steven Raphael, and Michael A. Stoll (2006). “Employers in the Boom: How Did the Hiring of Less-Skilled Workers Change during the 1990s?” Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 88 (May), pp. 283-99.

Howard, Greg, Robert Martin, and Beth Anne Wilson (2011). “Are Recoveries from Banking and Financial Crises Really So Different? (PDF)” International Finance Discussion Papers 1037. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, November.

Ilzetski, Ethan, and Keyu Jin (2013). “The Puzzling Change in the International Transmission of U.S. Macroeconomic Policy Shocks (PDF),” working paper. London: London School of Economics, February.

Justiniano, Alejandro, Giorgio Primiceri, and Andrea Tambalotti (2015). “Household Leveraging and Deleveraging,” Review of Economic Dynamics, vol. 18 (January), pp. 3-20.

Kaplan, Greg, Benjamin Moll, and Giovanni L. Violante (2016). “Monetary Policy According to HANK,” NBER Working Paper Series 21897. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, January.

Kashyap, Anil K., and Jeremy C. Stein (2000). “What Do a Million Observations on Banks Say about the Transmission of Monetary Policy?” American Economic Review, vol. 90 (June), pp. 407-28.

Katz, Lawrence F., and Alan B. Krueger (1999). “The High-Pressure U.S. Labor Market of the 1990s (PDF),” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 1, pp. 1-87.

Khan, Aubhik, and Julia K. Thomas (2013). “Credit Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations in an Economy with Production Heterogeneity,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 121 (December), pp. 1055-107.

Kiley, Michael T. (2008). “Monetary Policy Actions and Long-Run Inflation Expectations (PDF),” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2008-03. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, February.

Krueger, Dirk, Kurt Mitman, and Fabrizio Perri (2016). “Macroeconomics and Household Heterogeneity,” CEPR Discussion Paper 11038. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research, June.

Krusell, Per, and Anthony A. Smith, Jr. (1998). “Income and Wealth Heterogeneity in the Macroeconomy,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 106 (October), pp. 867-96.

Martin, Robert F., Teyanna Munyan, and Beth Anne Wilson (2015). “Potential Output and Recessions: Are We Fooling Ourselves? (PDF)” International Finance Discussion Papers 1145. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, September.

Mavroeidis, Sophocles, Mikkel Plagborg-Moller, and James H. Stock (2014). “Empirical Evidence on Inflation Expectations in the New Keynesian Phillips Curve,” Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 52 (March), pp. 124-88.

Mian, Atif, Kamalesh Rao, and Amir Sufi (2013). “Household Balance Sheets, Consumption, and the Economic Slump,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 128 (November), pp. 1687-726.

Mundell, Robert A. (1963). “Capital Mobility and Stabilization Policy under Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rates,” Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, vol. 29 (November), pp. 475-85.

Okun, Arthur M. (1973). “Upward Mobility in a High-Pressure Economy,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 1, pp. 207-52.

Parker, Jonathan A., Nicholas S. Souleles, David S. Johnson, and Robert McClelland (2013). “Consumer Spending and the Economic Stimulus Payments of 2008,” American Economic Review, vol. 103 (October), pp. 2530-53.

Peek, Joe, and Eric S. Rosengren (2013). “The Role of Banks in the Transmission of Monetary Policy,” Public Policy Discussion Papers 13-5. Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, September.

Peek, Joe, Eric S. Rosengren, and Geoffrey M.B. Tootell (2003). “Identifying the Macroeconomic Effects of Loan Supply Shocks,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 35 (December), pp. 931-46.

Quadrini, Vincenzo, and Jose-Víctor Rios-Rull (2015). “Inequality in Macroeconomics,” in Anthony B. Atkinson and Francois Bourguignon, eds., Handbook of Income Distribution, vol. 2B. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 1229-302.

Reifschneider, Dave, William Wascher, and David W. Wilcox (2015). “Aggregate Supply in the United States: Recent Developments and Implications for the Conduct of Monetary Policy,” IMF Economic Review, vol. 63 (May), pp. 71-109.

Siemer, Michael (2014). “Firm Entry and Employment Dynamics in the Great Recession (PDF),” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2014-56. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, August.

Solow, Robert M. (1997). “Is There a Core of Usable Macroeconomics We Should All Believe In?” American Economic Review, vol. 87 (May), pp. 230-32.

Sterk, Vincent, and Silvana Tenreyro (2016). “The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases (PDF),” CEP Working Paper 2016/1. Zurich: Council on Economic Policies, January.

Summers, Laurence H. (2014). “Reflections on the ‘New Secular Stagnation Hypothesis,'” in Coen Teulings and Richard Baldwin, eds., Secular Stagnation: Facts, Causes, and Cures. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research, pp. 27-38.

Yellen, Janet L. (2015). “Inflation Dynamics and Monetary Policy,” speech delivered at the Philip Gamble Memorial Lecture, University of Massachusetts at Amherst, Amherst, Mass., September 24.

Yellen, Janet L. (2016). “The Federal Reserve’s Monetary Policy Toolkit: Past, Present and Future,” speech delivered at “Designing Resilient Monetary Policy Frameworks for the Future,” a symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, held in Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August 26.

Footnotes

See Solow (1997).

Or, as Summers (2014) asked in a pithy inversion of Say’s law, is it true that “lack of demand creates lack of supply?” (p. 37).

As Blanchard and Summers (1986) discuss, the question at the time was whether the long-run equilibrium, or “natural,” rate of unemployment in European economies had been permanently raised by previous periods of high actual unemployment.

For example, see Cerra and Saxena (2008); Howard, Martin, and Wilson (2011); Martin, Nunyan, and Wilson (2014); and Blanchard, Cerutti, and Summers (2015).

See Reifschneider, Wascher, and Wilcox (2015).

Fernald (2015), however, argues that much of the apparent slowdown in U.S. potential GDP growth began prior to the 2007-09 recession.

See Okun (1973) for an early discussion of the benefits of a high-pressure economy. Importantly, not all of these benefits might show up as measured output, but they would nonetheless be welfare improving–for example, higher job satisfaction from better matches between workers and employers, as noted by Akerlof, Rose, and Yellen (1988).

For example, the experience of the 1990s might seem to provide a natural case study of whether reverse hysteresis is possible. Unfortunately, most studies of the labor market during this period do not directly speak to this issue, although Holzer, Raphael, and Stoll (2006) investigate changes in employers’ willingness to hire less-skilled workers during these years, while Katz and Krueger (1999) and my own study with Blinder (2001) explore the somewhat related question of how the U.S. economy was able to simultaneously experience rapid growth, low unemployment, and low inflation in the late 1990s.

See Krueger, Mitman, and Perri (2016).

On the role of financing constraints for firm employment, see Siemer (2014); Chodorow-Reich (2014); and Duygan-Bump, Levkov, and Montoriol-Garriga (2015). A general-equilibrium model with heterogeneity among firms and credit frictions is studied in Khan and Thomas (2013). For the role of entry and exit in macroeconomic dynamics, see Clementi and Palazzo (2016) as well as Gourio, Messer, and Siemer (2016).

For early quantitative work on the relationship between income and wealth heterogeneity and the macroeconomy, see Krusell and Smith (1998).

Guvenen (2011) reviews several issues related to macroeconomics with heterogeneity. For an overview of the interactions between distribution and aggregate outcomes, see the work by Quadrini and Rios-Rull (2015). For recent work on the effects of monetary policy in models with heterogeneous agents, see Kaplan, Moll, and Violante (2016); Gornemann, Kuester, and Nakajima (2016); Auclert (2016); and Sterk and Tenreyro (2016).

For an example of early research on this topic, see Bernanke and Gertler (1989). Other important pre-crisis studies include the development of the financial accelerato­r model by Bernanke and others (1999a) and work by Kashyap and Stein (2000) and Peek, Rosengren, and Tootell (2003) on the bank balance sheet channel and the effects of bank loan supply shocks. For a more recent summary of the role of banks in the monetary transmission mechanism, see Peek and Rosengren (2013). Chaney, Sraer, and Thesmer (2012) provide evidence for the collateral channel of real estate for corporate investment, while Mian, Rao, and Sufi (2013) examine the influence of household balance sheets on consumption.

More empirical work would be useful to disentangle the spending effects that result from changes in credit conditions from those that result from movements in interest rates, as estimates of the latter likely often inadvertently incorporate the former. Most empirical models of the overall economy do not explicitly control for the influence of noninterest credit factors on consumption and investment; as a result, estimated interest rate effects will partially reflect the influence of these factors to the extent these factors are correlated with interest rates. There are many reasons to suspect that this is the case. Movements in interest rates influence a firm’s cash flow and the value of its collateral, all else being equal. Higher interest rates also adversely affect consumer spending and especially residential investment, both by forcing households to devote a greater portion of their income to debt service and by making it more difficult to qualify for a loan because of maximum payment-to-income rules. Evidence for these effects is provided by Gertler and Karadi (2015), who show that relatively small changes in short-term interest rates are correlated with large movements in credit costs. Such correlations and interactions may explain why some types of spending appear to be more correlated with movements in nominal interest rates than with real interest rates; see Fair (2004, ch. 3) for evidence on this point. Finally, the relative contributions of relaxed lending standards, low interest rates, and other factors to housing bubbles, both in the United States and abroad, remains an open and unsettled topic; Agnello and Shucknecht (2011) present cross-country evidence that monetary policy plays an important role, while Dokko and others (2011) argue that monetary policy was a minor influence in the most recent episode.

See Mian, Rao, and Sufi (2013) for an assessment of the role of leverage and housing wealth shocks in driving consumption during the Great Recession. Work by Justiniano, Primiceri, and Tambalotti (2015) suggests that debt overhang alone cannot explain the slow recovery from the Great Recession.

See Yellen (2015) for a more extensive discussion.

In the economic literature, this general description of the inflation process is referred to as the expectations-augmented Phillips curve. In its simplest form, the Phillips curve relates inflation to expected inflation and the intensity of resource utilization in the economy. In practice, however, empirical specifications also typically include measures of supply shocks, such as changes in the relative prices of energy or imported goods, as additional determinants. Two well-known variants of the Phillips curve are the traditional “accelerationist” specification and the so-called New Keynesian Phillips curve; the former approximates inflation expectations using a moving average of past inflation, while the latter assumes that inflation expectations are “rational” and consistent with the predictions of a structural model of the entire economy. Some adherents of either type of Phillips curve argue that their preferred model can explain the behavior of inflation during and after the financial crisis. For example, Gordon (2013) presents evidence in favor of an accelerationist model, while Del Negro, Giannoni, and Schorfheide (2015) make this claim for a New Keynesian model.

See Blanchard (2016) for evidence on how the responsiveness of inflation to resource utilization has changed over time. Interestingly, research suggests that this sensitivity began declining well before the crisis.

For an early discussion of the potential macroeconomic effects of downward nominal wage rigidity, see Akerlof, Dickens, and Perry (1996). More recently, Daly and Hobijn (2014) develop a model in which the reluctance or inability of firms to cut nominal wages (or both) creates important nonlinearities in the relationship between labor utilization and wage inflation. Finally, Fallick, Lettau, and Wascher (2015) review the evidence for downward nominal wage rigidity in recent years and explore the ways in which it has interacted with labor market stress over time.

Specifically, survey measures of long-run inflation expectations are broadly correlated with estimates of inflation’s longer-term trend. See Clark and Davig (2008); see also Faust and Wright (2013, who make a related point in the context of inflation forecasting.

As Mavroeidis, Plagborg-Moller, and Stock (2014) conclude from their exhaustive survey, empirical estimates of the New Keynesian inflation equation are “unable to pin down the role of expectations in the inflation process sufficiently accurately for the results to be useful for policy analysis” (p. 172).

For a discussion of the theoretical and empirical influence of monetary policy on inflation in the context of a formal inflation-targeting regime, see Bernanke and others (1999b).

See Kiley (2008) for a discussion of the relationship between U.S. monetary policy and survey measures of long-run inflation expectations; his results suggest that it took many years for the Federal Reserve to succeed in anchoring long-run expectations at a low level. In a similar vein, Bernanke and others (1999b) conclude that inflation expectations “respond only after a lag following declines in [actual] inflation” (p. 298) based on their study of the effects of adopting inflation targeting in different countries.

I discussed this likelihood in a recent speech (Yellen, 2016).

See Mundell (1963) and Fleming (1962).

See Ammer, De Pooter, Erceg, and Kamin (2016). Other recent research on this topic includes Fukuda, Kimura, Sudo, and Ugai (2013); Georgiadis (2015); Glick and Leduc (2015); and Ilzetski and Jin (2013).

The post The Elusive ‘Great’ Recovery: Causes & Implications for Future Business Cycle Dynamics appeared first on InvestAdvocate.

Show more