2015-01-27

‎Not proofread: Created page with "<section begin="s1"/>became due and were paid, most of the cash being available for borrowers a few hours after it was paid in by the holders of the scrip which represented th..."

New page

<noinclude><pagequality level="1" user="Slowking4" /><div class="pagetext">{{rh|{{x-larger|734 }}|{{x-larger|{{uc|MARKET BOSWORTH—MARKHAM, SIR C. R.}}}}|{{x-larger| }}}}<!-- replace "Foo" and "Bar" with the header from the page, delete and input page numbers are appropriate -->

</noinclude><section begin="s1"/>became due and were paid, most of the cash being available

for borrowers a few hours after it was paid in by the holders of

the scrip which represented the loans until the definitive bonds

were ready. The task of dealing with cash forming instalments

of the loans was not, however, the only problem before the banks

which issued them. As the scrip of each loan gradually became

“ fully paid ” the proceeds of the loan in the hands of the banks

became a very large sum. The japanese government held the

whole of it at its disposal, and might have seriously embarrassed

the London money market if it had not dealt with its

huge balances considerately. The Japanese government had

promised not to withdraw any portion of the loans raised in

London in gold, but it was under no restrictions as to how it

should employ the money lying to its account. It might have

kept it locked up until it had a bill for ships or clothing to pay.

As might be expected, the government from the outset transferred

a portion of what was deposited with the banks to the

Bank of England, finding it advantageous on various grounds

to do so. The remainder was lent for short periods by the banks,

but for some time no means were available for lending for any

considerable length of time, though the Japanese government

had no immediate use for the whole of it. It was suggested to

the government by its advisers that it would be a convenience

to the money market, and no inconvenience to Japanese policy,

if any balances which were not likely to be wanted for some

months were invested in British treasury bills, and the government,

after fully acquainting itself with the nature of the operation,

agreed to it. The plan was found to work well; it released

for definite periods money that would otherwise have been of

little use to the money market, and it was of pecuniary benefit

to the Japanese exchequer to the extent of the interest earned

by the portion of the balances so employed. Incidentally it

suited the British treasury; the Japanese demand, which became

a constant feature in connexion with treasury bill issues, lowered

the discount rates at which “ sixes ” were placed. The Japanese

not only applied for treasury bills and bought them in the market,

but they also took up some of the exchequer bonds issued in

connexion with the South African war towards the end of their

currency, thus relieving the money market of a further part of

the weight of British government paper which it would otherwise

have had to take on itself. A further important development

of lapanese management of its London balances took place in

1906, when a portion of these balances was placed under the

control of agents of the Bank of England, to be lent, or not lent,

in the market as suited the Bank's policy, which was at that

time directed to raising the value of money in order to protect

and increase its reserve. The plan worked very well on the whole.

It was merely an adaptation of a practice initiated some years

before, whereby the Bank sometimes obtained temporary control

of moneys belonging to the India Council. The same idea, that

of “ intercepting ” market funds, which were beating down the

discount rate, depressing the foreign exchanges and depleting

the Bank's reserve, has been employed in regard to the clearing

banks themselves, the banks having on more than one occasion

agreed to lend the Bank of England a certain portion of their

balances.

The discount houses, though an important body of institutions,

are not of so much importance as they were before 1866, when

they suifered a serious blow through the failure of

Th' “ Overend's, ” from which as a body they have never

Discount . .

H°, , s, , fully recovered. The five large concerns which still

exist are, however, very powerful and exercise considerable

influence on the market. They hold considerable

quantities of bills at all times; occasionally their holdings are

very large, but they turn out the contents of their bill cases

readily if they think fit. Their business is different in practice

from that of the smaller “ bill-brokers, ” who usually are what

their name suggests, namely, persons who do not hold many

bills, but find them for banks who need them, charging a small

commission. The small bill-brokers borrow from the Bank of

England much more freely than the big discount houses. The

latter only “ go to the bank ” in ordinary times perhaps once or

twice a year. During the South African War, which disturbed

the money market very much, they obtained accommodation

from the Bank more frequently than usual. The small brokers

almost always have to borrow from the Bank at the end of

every quarter, when money is scarce owing to the regular

quarterly requirements of business, and also, to some extent,

because certain of the banks make it a practice to call in loans

at the end of each month in order to show a satisfactory cash

reserve in their monthly balance-sheet. This practice is not

approved by the best authorities, for although it does no great

harm in quiet times, the banks who follow it might find it

difficult, or even impossible, to call in their loans in times ef

severe stringency.

{{sc|Authorities}}.”-Walt€f Bagehot, Lombard Street (1873); Arthur

Ellis, Rationale of Market Flnctations; Robert Giiien, Stock Exchange

Securities (18 9); W. Stanley jevons, Theory of Political Economy

(2nd ed., 1879§ , pp. QI seq., and Investigations in Currency and Finance;

Henry Sidgwick, Principles of Political Economy, book ii. ch. ii.;

Augustin Cournot, Theory of Wealth (1838), translated by Nathaniel

T. Bacon; George Clare, A Money Market Primer and Key to the

Exchanges; John Stuart Mill, Principles of Political Economy, book

iii. ch. i.-vi.; John Shield Nicholson, Bankers' Money; Hartley

Withers, The Meaning of Money (1909). (W. Ho.)

<section end="s1"/>

<section begin="s2"/>'''MARKET BOSWORTH''', a market town in the Bosworth

parliamentary division of Leicestershire, England; ro 5 m.

N.N.W. from London on a branch from Nuneaton of the London

& North Western and Midland railways, near the Ashby-dela-Zouch

canal. Pop. (1901), 659. The church of St Peter is

Perpendicular, with a lofty tower and Spire. At the grammar

school, founded in 1528, Dr Samuel Johnson was a master about

1732, but found the work unbearable. The trade of Market

Bosworth is principally agricultural, and there are brick works.

Two miles south is the scene of the battle of Bosworth, in 1485,

where Richard III. fell before Henry earl of Richmond, who

thereupon assumed the crown as Henry VII.

<section end="s2"/>

<section begin="s3"/>'''MARKET DRAYTON''', a market town in the Newport division

of Shropshire, England, on the river Tern and the Shropshire

Union canal, 178 m. N.W. from London. Pop. (civil parish of

Drayton-in-Hales, 1901), 5167. The Wellington-Crewe line of

the Great Western railway is here joined by a branch into

Staffordshire of the North Staffordshire railway. The church of

St Mary has Norman remains but is modernised by restoration.

The town is a centre of agricultural trade, and there are large

iron foundries. It is in the parish of Drayton-in-Hales, a name

sometimes applied to it; and it is also known as Drayton Magna.

It is an ancient town, of which the manor was held successively

by the abbots of St Ebrulph in Normandy and Combermere in

Cheshire. On Blore Heath, 3 m. east'in Staffordshire, Audley

Cross marks a great battle in the Wars of the Roses (1459), in

which the Yorkists were successful and Lord Audley fell.

<section end="s3"/>

<section begin="s5"/>'''MARKET HARBOROUGH''', a market town in the Harborough parliamentary division of Leicestershire, England; on the river

Welland and the Grand Union Canal. Pop. of urban district

(1901), 7735. It is 81 m. N.N.W. from London by the Midland

railway, and is served by branches of the London & North

Western and Great Northern railways. The church of

St Dionysius is Decorated and Perpendicular, with a fine

tower and spire. The grammar school was founded in

1614; it occupies modern buildings, but the original house

remains, a picturesque half-timbered building, raised upon

pillars of wood. Both British and Roman remains have

been found in the vicinity. There are malt-houses and boot,

shoe and stay factories. The town is also an important

fox-hunting centre.

<section end="s5"/>

<section begin="s6"/>'''MARKHAM, SIR CLEMENTS ROBERT''' (1830-), English

traveller, geographer and author, son of the Rev. David F. Markham, canon of Windsor, and of Catherine, 'daughter of Sir W. Milner, Bart., of Nunappleton, Yorkshire, was born on the zoth of July 1830 at Stillingfleet, near York, and educated at Westminster

School. He entered the navy in 1844, became midshipman

in 1846, and passed for a lieutenant in 185I.» In 1850-1851 he served on the Franklin search expedition in' the'Arctic regions, under Captain Austin. He retired from the navy in 1852, and in<section end="s6"/><noinclude><references/></div></noinclude>

Show more